Monday, June 3, 2019
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
Capital As find Pricing Model (CAPM)1. IntroductionMarkowtiz (1952) did the ground defecate for the CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model). From the study of the archean theories we know that the bump of an be protective covering system is measured by the standard deviation of its be off or drive off. Therefore, for a larger put on the line we allow have high standard deviation of the respective security translate. Markowtiz pleadd that the standard deviations of security slip bys for every two securities argon not additive if they atomic number 18 combined to constructher unless(prenominal) the checks of those two pluss argon perfectly positively correlated. He to a fault observed that the standard deviation of security egest of a portfolio is less than the sum of the standard deviation of those summations constituted the portfolio. Markowitz developed the streamlined frontier of portfolio, the economical set from where the investors select the portfolio which is most capable for them. Technic onlyy, an investor will hold a mean- deviation efficient portfolio which will afford the highest pay off to them with a given level of edition. Markowitzs computation of try reduction is very rigorous and tedious. Sharpe (1964) developed the unmarried index nonplus which is computation eachy efficient. He derived a parking lot index where the asset restoproportionn is related with the common index. This common index undersurface be either variable which has influence on the asset return. We can apply this single index exercise to the portfolio as well since the expected return of a portfolio is the weighted average of the expected returns of the constituents of the portfolio.When we need to analyze the risk of an individual security, we have to consider the early(a) securities of the portfolio as well. Beca call, we ar disported close to the additional risk being added to the portfolio when one addition security is added to the portfol io. Thus the concept of risk share of an individual security to the portfolio is antithetic from the risk of that security itself. An investor faces two mannikins of risks. One is called the systematic risk and the other is know as unsystematic risk. Unsystematic risk is a conformation of risk which can be minimized or eliminated by increasing the size of the portfolio, namely, by increasing the diversity of the portfolio. The systematic risk is well cognize as the market risk. Because, it depends on the overall movement of the market and the financial condition of the whole economy. By diversifying the portfolio, we cannot eliminate the systematic risk. conjecturally CAPM offers very positive predictions approximately how to measure risk and return birth. However, the confirmable present of CAPM is not very encouraging. One may conclude that these failings are rooted in execrable construction of the prototype but once can argue that this failing arises because of the dif ficulties of building comprehensive and valid foot raceify lay. The estimation st appreciategy of CAPM is not costless from the data-snooping bias. Because of the non-experimental nature of economic theory we cannot avoid this problem. Moreover a lot of investigations already have been done to test the validity of the CAPM. Thus, no attempt has been do in this paper to test the validity of the model. Here in this paper we will critically examine some literatures on CAPM testing. We will begin with agreement the model. We will briefly outline some mathematics required to understand the underlying assumptions of the model. Then we will focus on the single and multi-factor CAPM models to analyze the model assumptions and restrictions required to hold these models to be true.2. The Capital Asset Pricing Model ExplainedIn 1959 Markowitz introduced the notion of mean-variance efficient portfolio. According to him it is optimal for an investor to hold a mean-variance efficient portfo lio. The mean-variance efficient portfolio is a portfolio for an investor where he minimizes the portfolio return, given the expected return and maximizes expected return, given the variance. Later Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965b) further developed the work of Markowitz. In their work it has been showed that if the investors expectations are homogeneous and when the hold the mean-variance efficient portfolio past in the nonexistence of market friction the market portfolio will be a mean-variance efficient portfolio.There are two basic building blocks to derive the CAPM one is the capital market line (CML) and the other one is the security market line (SML). In CAPM the securities are priced in a air where the expected risks are compensated by the expected returns. As we will be investigating different form of CAPM in this work it is worthy to review the basic notions of CML and SML.The capital market line (CML) conveys the return of an investor for his portfolio. As we have alrea dy mentioned, there is a linear relationship exists amongst the risk and return on the efficient portfolio that can be written as ascertainsOn the Other hit the SML specifies the return what an individual expects in terminal figures of a risk- discontinue rate and the relative risk of a portfolio. The SML with security i can be represented as followsHere the measurable is interpreted as the amount of non-diversifiable risk intrinsic in the security relative to the risk of the efficient market portfolio.The utility function of the market broker is either quadratic or normalAll the diversifiable risks are eliminatedThe efficient market portfolio and the risk-free assets dominate the opportunity set of the risky asset.We can use the security market line can be employ to test whether the securities are fairly priced.3. The Logic of the ModelTo understand the logic of CAPM, let us consider a portfolio M. To clear the asset market this portfolio must be on the efficient frontier . Thus the underlying concept that is true for token(prenominal) variance portfolio, must be true for the market portfolio as well. With the borderline variance condition for portfolio M when there are N risky assets, we can relieve the minimum variance condition by the sideline equationWhere is the expected return on the asset i and . The market genus Beta for the asset is derived by dividing the covariance of the market return and individual asset return by the variance of the market return,In the minimum variance condition stands for the expected asset return whose market important is zero which implies that the asset return is not correlated with the market return. The second term of the equation represents the risk premium. Here the beta measures how culture medium the asset return is with the variation in the market return. Sharpe and Lintner foc utilize on three important implications. They are 1)the kibosh is zero 2) Beta can wholly capture the cross sectioned varia tion of expected access asset return and, 3)The market risk premium is positive.Sharpe and Lintner in their CAPM model assumed that the pay off from a risky asset is uncorrelated with the market return. In their model the beta becomes zero when the the covariance of a asset return offsets the variance of the other assets returns. When the borrowing and change is risk free and when the asset return is not correlated with the market return then the asset return equals the risk free rate. In the Sharpe-Lintner model the relationship between the asset return and the beta is represented by the following equationHowever, this assumption of riskless borrowing and lending is unrealistic. Black (1972) developed a CAPM model where he did not make this extreme assumption. He showed that the mean variance efficient portfolio can be obtained by allowing the short selling of the risky assets. The Black and Sharpe-Lintner model differ in terms of the . Black observed that has to be less than the expected market return which allows the premium for the market beta to be positive. In the Sharpe-Lintner model the expect return was the risk free interest rate. The assumption that Black made about short selling is not realistic either. Because, if there is no risky asset (Sharpe-Lintner version) and if there is unrestricted short selling of the risky asset (Black version) then the efficient portfolio is actually not efficient and there does not exist any relation between market beta and CAPM (Fama and cut 2003). So, the CAPM models are strengthened on some extreme assumptions. To testify the validity of these models researchers have tested the model against the market data. In this paper we will investigate some of those empirical researches.4. Literature on CAPM testingThere are three relationships between expected return and market beta which is implied by the model. First, the expected returns on all the underlying assets are linearly related to their respective betas. Secon d, the premium for beta is positive which implies that the expected return on the market portfolio exceeds the expected return on assets. Moreover, the returns of these assets are uncorrelated with the expected return of market portfolio. Third, in the Sharpe-Lintner model we see that the underlying assets which are uncorrelated with the market portfolio have the expected returns which are equal to the risk neutral interest rate. In that model, if we subtract the risk free rate from the expected market return, we get the beta premium. Conventionally the tests of CAPM are establish on those three implications mentioned above.4.1 Tests on Risk PremiumsMost of the previous cross-section degene proportionalityn tests primarily focus on the Sharpe-Lintner models findings about the concept and the slope term which studies the relationship between expected return and the market beta. In that model they regressed the mean asset returns on the estimated asset betas. The model suggests that the ageless term in the cross-section retroflexion stands for the risk free interest rate and the slope term stands for the difference between market interest rate and risk free interest rate.There are some demerits of the study. First of all, the estimated betas for individual assets are imprecise which creates the measurement error when we use them to formulate average returns. Secondly, the error term in the regression has some common sources of variation which produces positive correlation among the residuals. Thus the regression has the downward bias in the usual OLS estimate. Blume (1970) and Black, Scholes and Jensen (1972) worked on overcoming the shortcomings of Sharpe-Lintner model. Instead of working on the individual securities they worked on the portfolios. They combined the expected returns and market beta in a similar way that if the CAPM can explain the security return, it can in addition explain portfolio return. As the econometric theory suggests, the estimate d beta for diversified portfolios are more ideal than the estimated beta for the individual security. Therefore, if we use the market portfolio in the regression of average return on betas, it lessens the critical problem. However, assemblying shrinks the range of estimated betas and shrinks the statistical power as well. To fishing tackle this researchers sort securities to create two portfolios. The first one contains securities with the lowest beta and it moves up to the highest beta.We know that when there exists a correlation among the residuals of the regression model, we cannot draw accurate inference from that. Fama and Macbeth (1973) suggested a method to address this inference problem. They ran the regression of returns on beta based on the monthly data rather than estimating a single cross-section regression of the average returns on beta. In this approach the standard error of the means and the time series means can be used to check whether the average premium for bet a is positive and whether the return on the asset is equal to the average risk free interest rate.Jensen (1968) noted that Sharpe-Lintner model also implies a time series regression test. According to Sharpe-Lintner model, the average realized CAPM risk premium explains the average value of an assets overplus return. The intercept term in the regression entails that Jensens alpha. The time series regression takes the following formIn early studies we reject Sharpe-Lintner model for CAPM. Although there exists a positive relation between average return and beta, its too flat. In Sharpe-Lintner model the intercept stands for the risk free rate and the slope term indicates the expected market return in access of the risk neutral rate. In that regression model the intercept is greater than the risk neutral rate and the coefficient on beta is less than . In Jensens study the p value for the thirty years consummation is 0.02 only which indicates that the unreal hypothesis is rejected a t 5% significance level. The five and ten year sub-period demonstrates the strongest evidence against the restrictions imposed by the model.In past several studies it has been support that the relationship in between average return and beta is too flat (Blume 1970 and Stambaugh 1982). With the low betas the constant term in the time series regression of excess asset return on excess market return are positive and it becomes negative for the high betas of the underlying assets.In the Sharpe-Linter model, it has been predicted that portfolios are plot along a straight line where the intercept equals the risk free rate, , and the slope equals to the expected excess return on the market rate . Fama and French (2004) observed that risk premium for beta (per unit) is lower than the Sharpe-Lintner model and the relationship between asset return and beta is linear. The Black version of CAPM also observes the same where it predicts only the beta premium is positive.4.2 Testing the ability o f market betas of explaining expected returnsBoth the Sharpe-Lintner and Black model predict that market portfolio is mean-variance efficient. The mean-variance efficiency implies that the difference in market beta explains the difference in expected return of the securities and portfolios. This prediction plays a very important component part in testing the validity of the CAPM.In the study by Fama and Macbeth (1973), we can add pre-determined informative variables to the month wise cross section regressions of asset return on the market beta. Provided that all the differences in expected return are explained by the betas, the coefficients of any additional variable should not be dependably different from zero. So, in the cross-section analysis the important thing is to carefully choose the additional variable. In this regard we can take the ex gigantic of the study by Fama and MacBeth (1973). In that work the additional variables are squared betas. These variables have no impact in explaining the average asset return.By using the time series regression we can also test the hypothesis that market betas completely explain expected asset return. As we have already mentioned that in the time series regression analysis, the constant term is the difference between the assets average return and the excess return predicted by the Sharpe-Lintner model. We cannot group assets in portfolios where the constant term is dependably different from zero and this applies only the model holds true. For example, for a portfolio, the constant term for a high earning to price ratio and low earning to price ratio should be zero. Therefore, in order to test the hypothesis that betas suffice to explain expected returns, we can estimate the time-series regression for the portfolios and then test the joint hypothesis for the intercepts against zero. In this kind of approach we have to choose the form of the portfolio in a way which will depict any limitation of the CAPM prediction.I n past literatures, researchers tend to follow different kinds of tests to see whether the constant term in the time-series regression is zero. However, it is very debatable to conclude about the best small sample properties of the test. Gibbons, Shanken and Ross (1989) came up with an F-test for the constant term that has the exact-small sample properties and which is asymptotically efficient as well.For the tangency portfolio, this F-test builds an entrant by combining the market proxy and the average value of an assets excess return. Then we can test if the efficient set and the risk free asset is superior to that one obtained by combining the market proxy and risk free asset alone. From the study of Gibbons, Ross, and Shanken (1989) we can also test whether market betas are sufficient enough to explain the expected returns. The statistical test what is conventionally done is if the explanatory variables can identify the returns which are not explained by the market betas. We can use the market proxy and the left hand side of the regression we can construct a test to see if the market proxy lies on the minimum variance frontier.All these early tests rattling do not test the CAPM. These tests actually tested if market proxy is efficient which can be constructed from it and the left hand side of the time series regression used in the statistical test. Its noteworthy here that the left hand side of the time series regression does not include all marketable assets and it is really very difficult to get the market portfolio data (Roll, 1977). So, many researchers concluded that the prospect of testing the validity of CAPM is not very encouraging.From the early literatures, we can conclude that the market betas are sufficient enough to explain expected returns which we see from the Black version of CAPM. That model also predicts that the respective risk premium for beta is positive also holds true. But at the same time the prediction made by Sharpe and Lintner t hat the risk premium beta is derived from subtracting the risk free interest rate from the expected return is rejected. The attractive part of the black model is, it is easily tractable and very appealing for empirical testing.4.3 modern Tests on CAPMRecent investigations started in the late 1970s have also challenged the success of the Black version of the CAPM. In recent empirical literatures we see that there are other sources are variation in expected returns which do not have any significant impact on the market betas. In this regard Basus (1977) work is very significant. He shows that if we sort the stocks according to earning-price ratios, then the future returns on high earning-price ratios are significantly higher than the return in CAPM. Instead of sorting the stocks by E/P, if we sort it by market capitalisation then the mean returns on small stocks are higher than the one in CAPM (Banz, 1981) and if we do the same by book-to-market equity ratios then the set of stocks w ith higher ratio gives higher average return (Statman and Rosenberg, 1980).The ratios have been used in the above mentioned literatures associate the stock prices which involves the information about expected returns which are not captured by the market betas. The price of the stock does not altogether depend on the cash flows, rather it depends on the present discounted value of the cash flow. So, the different kind of ratios discussed above play a crucial role in analyzing the CAPM. In line with this Fama and French (1992) empirically analyzed the failure of the CAPM and concluded that the above mentioned ratios have impact on stock return which is provided by the betas. In a time series regression analysis they concluded the same thing. They also observed that the relationship between the average return and the beta is even flatter after the sample periods on which early CAPM studies were done. Chan, Hamao, and Lakonishok (1991) observed a strong significant relationship between book-to-market equity and asset return for Japanese data which is consistent with the findings of Fama and French (1992) implies that the contradictions of the CAPM associated with price ratios are not sample specific.5. Efficient Set of MathematicsThe mathematics of mean-variance efficient set is known as the efficient set of mathematics. To test the validity of the CAPM, one of the most important parts is to test the mean-variance efficiency of the model. Thus, it is very important to understand the underlying mathematics of the model. Here, we will discuss some of the useful results of it (Roll, 1977).Here we assume that there are N risky assets with a mean vector and a covariance matrix . In addition we also assume that the covariance matrix is of full rank. is vector of the portfolio weight. This portfolio has the average return and variance. Portfolio p is the minimum variance portfolio with the mean return if its portfolio weight vector is the solution to the following cons trained optimizationWe solve this minimization problem by setting the Lagrangian function. Lets define the followingThe efficient frontier can be generated from any two minimum variance portfolios. Let us assume that p and r be any two minimum variance portfolio. The covariance of these two portfolios is as followsFor a global minimum-variance portfolio g we have the followingThe covariance of the asset return of the global minimum portfolio g and any other portfolio as defined as a is as followsFor a multiple regression of the return of an asset or portfolio on any minimum variance portfolio except the global minimum variance portfolio and underlying zero-beta portfolio we have the followingThe above mentioned result deserves some more attention. Here we will prove the result. As . The result is obvious. So, we just need to show thatand . Let us assume that r be the minimum variance portfolio with expected return . From the minimization problem we can write the followingPortfolio a can be expressed as a combination of portfolio r and an arbitrage portfolio which is tranquil of portfolio a minus portfolio . The return of is expressed asSince , the expected return of is zero. Because, as mentioned earlier that it is an arbitrage portfolio with an expected return of zero, for a minimum variance portfolio q. We have the following minimization problemThe solution to the optimization problem is c=0. Any other solution will contradict q from being the minimum variance.Since, , thus taking the derivative gives the following expressionSetting the derivative equal to zero and by substituting in the solution c=0 givesThus the return of is uncorrelated with the return of all other minimum variance portfolio.Another important assumption of the CAPM is if the market portfolio is the tangency portfolio then the intercept of the excess return market model is zero. Here we will prove the result. Let us consider the following model with the IID assumptions of the error term i nstantly by taking the unconditional expectation we get,As we have showed above, the weight vector of the market portfolio is,Using this weight vector, we can calculate the covariance matrix of asset and portfolio returns, the expected excess return and the variance of the market return,Combining these results provide,Now, by combining the expression for beta and the expression for the expected excess return give,Therefore, the ready result is6. Single-factor CAPIn practice, to check the validity of the CAPM we test the SML. Although CAPM is a single period ex-ante model, we rely on the realised returns. The reason being the ex ante returns are unobservable. So, the question which becomes so obvious to ask is does the past security return conform to the theoretical CAPM?We need to estimate the security feature of speech line (SCL) in order to investigate the beta. Here the SCL considers the excess return on a specific security j to the excess return on some efficient market index at time t. The SCL can be written as followsHere is the constant term which represents the asset return (constant) and is an estimated value of . We use this estimated value as an explanatory variable in the following cross-sectional regressionConventionally this regression is used to test for a positive risk return trade off. The coefficient of is significantly different from zero and is assumed to be positive in order to hold the CAPM to be true. This also represents the market price of risk. When we test the validity of CAPM we test if is true estimate of . We also test whether the model specification of CAPM is correct.The CAPM is single period model and they do not have any time dimension into the model. So, it is important to assume that the returns are IID and jointly multivariate normal. The CAPM is very useful in predicting stock return. We also assume that investors can borrow and lend at a risk free rate. In the Black version of CAPM we assume that zero-beta portfolio is unobservable and thus becomes an unknown parameter. In the Black model the unconstrained model is the real-return market model. Here we also have the IID assumptions and the joint normality return.Many early studies (e.g. Lintner, 1965 Douglas, 1969) on CAPM focus on individual security returns. The empirical results are off-putting. Miler and Scholes (1972) instal some statistical setback faced when using individual securities in analyzing the validity of the CAPM. Although, some of the studies have overcome the problems by using portfolio returns. In the study by Black,Jensen and Scholes (1972) on New York stock exchange data, portfolios had been formed and reported a linear relationship between the beta and average excess portfolio return. The intercept approaches to be negative (Positive) for the beta greater than one (less than one). Thus a zero beta version was developed of the CAPM model. The model was developed in a model where the intercept term is allowed to take differ ent values in different period. Fama and Mcbeth (1973) panoptic the work of Black et al (1972). They showed the evidence of a larger intercept than the risk neutral rate. They also found that a linear relationship exists between the average returns and the beta. It has also been observed that this linear relation becomes stronger when we work with a dataset for a long period. However, other subsequent studies provide weak empirical evidence of this zero beta version.We have mixed findings about the asset return and beta relationship based on the past empirical research. If the portfolio used as a market proxy is inefficient then the single factor CAPM is rejected. This is also true if the proxy portfolio is inefficient by a little tolerance (Roll 1977, Ross 1977). Moreover, there exists survivorship bias in the data used in testing the validity of CAPM (Sloan, 1995). Bos and Newbold (1984) observed that beta is not stable for a period of time. Moreover, there are issues with the m odel specifications too. Amihud, Christen and Mendelson (1993) observed that there are errors in variables and these errors have impact on the conclusion of the empirical research.We experience less favourable evidence for CAPM in the late 1970s in the so called anomalies literature. We can think the anomalies as the farm characteristics which can be used to group assets in order to have a high ex post Sharpe ratio relative to the ratio of the market proxy for the tangency portfolio. These characteristics provide explanatory power for the cross-section of the average mean returns beyond the beta of the CAPM which is a contradiction to the prediction of CAPM.We have already mentioned that the early anomalies include the size establish and P/E ratio as we have already mentioned. Basu (1977) observed that the portfolio formed on the basis of P/E ratio is more efficient than the portfolio formed according to the mean-variance efficiency. With a lower P/E firms have higher sample averag e return and with high P/E ratio have lower mean return than would be the case if the market portfolio is mean-variance efficient. On the other hand the size effect shows that low market capitalization firms have higher sample return than would be expected if the market portfolio was mean-variance efficient.Fama and French (1992,1993) observed that beta cannot explain the difference between the portfolio formed based on ratio of book value of equity to the market value of equity. Firm has higher average return for higher book market ratio than originally predicted by the CAPM. However, these results signal economically deviations from CAPM. In these anomalies literatures, there are hardly any motivations to study the farm characteristics. Thus there is a supposition of overstating the evidence against the CAPM since there are sample selection bias problem in estimating the model and also there is a problem of data snooping bias. This a kind of bias refers to the biases in drawing t he statistical inference that arises from data to conduct subsequent research with the same or related kind of data. ingest selection bias is rooted if we exclude certain sample of stocks from our analysis. Sloan (1995) argued that data requirements for the study of book market ratios lead to failing stocks being excluded which results the survivorship bias.Despite an ample amount of evidences against CAPM, it is still being widely used in finance. There is also the controversy exists about how we should interpret the evidence against the CAPM. Some researchers often argue that CAPM should be replaced with multifactor model with different sources of risks. In the following section we will analyze the multifactor model.7. Multifactor ModelsSo far we have not talked anything about the cross sectional variation. In many studies we have found that market data alone cannot explain the cross sectional variation in average security returns. In the analysis of CAPM, some variables like, ra tio of book-to-market value, price-earning ratio, macroeconomic variables, etc are treated as the fundamental variables. The presence of these variables account for the cross-sectional variation in expected returns. Theoretical arguments also signal that more than one factor are required.Fama and French (1995), in their study showed that the difference between the return of small stock and huge stock portfolio (SMB) and the difference between high and low book-to-market stock portfolio (HML) become useful factor in cross sectional analysis of the equity returns. Chung, Johnson and Schill (2001) found that the SMB and HML become statistically insignificant if higher order co-moments are included in the cross sectional portfolio return analysis. We can infer from here that the SMB and HML can be considered as good proxies for the higher order co-moments. Ferson and Harvey (1999) made a point that many econometric model specifications are rejected because they have the aim of ignorin g conditioning information.Now we will show one of the very important results of the multifactor model. Let us consider a regression of portfolio on the returns of any set of portfolios from which the entire minimum variance boundary can be generated. We will show that the intercept of this regression will be zero and that factor regression coefficients for any asset will sum to unity. Let the number of the portfolios in the set be K and is the (Kx1) vector of time period t of asset returns. For any value of the constant , there exists a combination of portfolio and assets. Let us consider be the global minimum variance portfolio and we denote the portfolio as op. Corresponding to op is minimum variance portfolio p which is uncorrelated with the return of op. As long as p and op are efficient portfolios in terms of the minimum variance their returns are the linear combinations of the elements of ,where and are (Kx1) vectors of portfolio weights. As p and op are minimum variance por tfolio their returns are linear combinations of the elements of ,Then for the K portfolios we have,By rearranging, we get the following,Substituting this value into returns the followingNow let us consider a multivariate regression of N assets on K factor portfolios,where a
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.